CHAPTER 4: UNPACKING SUPPLY – FROM FACTORY TO SHELF

CHAPTER 4: UNPACKING SUPPLY – FROM FACTORY TO SHELF
Objective:
To analytically reconstruct the supply function using variables such as
cost, time, logistics, inventory behavior, perishability, and policy
disruptions. This chapter aims to understand how supply functions respond
dynamically to internal and external shocks.
4.1 Understanding the Nature of Supply
In economics, the supply function denotes the relationship
between the quantity of goods a producer is willing to supply and various
influencing factors, primarily the market price. However, in a real-world
framework, supply is far from linear or static. Modern supply chains are
affected by cost structure, policy changes, inventory cycles, transportation
delays, and demand unpredictability.
The basic supply function is often written as:
Qs = a + bP – cC + dT + eL – fS
Where:
·
Qs: Quantity supplied
·
P: Price of the product
·
C: Production cost
·
T: Technology index or time
efficiency
·
L: Logistics infrastructure
·
S: Seasonality or perishability
·
a, b, c, d, e, f: Sensitivity
coefficients
This function tells us that supply increases with price and technological
improvements, while it decreases with higher costs, poor logistics, and
perishability risks.
4.2 Components Influencing Supply
1. Production Costs (C)
Cost remains the most sensitive determinant. Higher input prices,
especially for raw materials, fuel, and labor, decrease the margin and thus
reduce willingness to supply.
For example, during the global oil shock, production costs surged, leading to a
leftward shift in the supply curve.
Equation Insight:
If Qs = 50 + 4P – 2C, and cost increases from ₹10 to ₹20 while P = ₹15,
Then Qs changes from 50 + 4(15) – 2(10) = 100
To Qs = 50 + 4(15) – 2(20) = 80
Interpretation: A ₹10 increase in cost reduced supply by 20
units.
2. Lead Time (T)
The time lag between initiating production and delivery
affects supply elasticity. In industries like automotive or electronics, long
lead times reduce the ability to respond quickly to market signals.
Companies now use Just-in-Time (JIT) systems to reduce
inventory holding costs but risk greater disruption sensitivity.
3. Perishability (S)
For sectors such as agriculture or dairy, perishability
restricts storage and affects seasonal supply availability. Supply here depends
on storage tech, weather, and consumer behavior.
E.g., tomato supply in monsoon drops drastically due to spoilage risks.
4. Government Policy & Regulation
Subsidies, taxes, and quotas impact supply. A favorable GST regime for
textiles has enhanced supply, while regulatory bottlenecks in pharma often
curtail it.
5. Logistics & Inventory Behavior (L)
A strong logistics chain—cold storage, container trucks, last-mile
delivery—enhances market reach. Inventory behavior like safety stock
or economic order quantity (EOQ) models affect short-term
availability.
4.3 Supply Curve Shifts – Graphical Interpretation
Supply curves shift based on non-price determinants like
cost changes, policy revisions, or logistics bottlenecks.
Graph Concept:
Plot Quantity Supplied (Qs) on the X-axis and Price (P) on the Y-axis.
·
Initial supply curve: S₀
·
After increase in input costs or logistics
disruption: Curve shifts left to S₁
·
After technology improvement or subsidy: Curve
shifts right to S₂
🟩 Graphical Summary:
plaintext
CopyEdit
Price
|
| S
₁
S
₀
S
₂
| \ \ \
| \ \ \
| \ \ \
| \ \ \
|-------------------------------> Quantity Supplied
4.4 Case Study: Supply Chain Shock in Pharma During COVID-19
Background
India is a major producer of generic drugs, but 70% of its active
pharmaceutical ingredients (APIs) are imported from China. During the
first wave of COVID-19, lockdowns in Wuhan disrupted API
supply chains.
Impact
·
Lead time extended from 3 weeks
to over 8 weeks.
·
Inventory backlogs and hoarding
occurred.
·
Prices of common drugs increased by 30–50%.
·
Government introduced temporary export bans to
secure domestic supply.
Supply Curve Effect
The supply curve of pharma products shifted left,
reflecting reduced availability despite rising prices.
Learning Point: The pandemic highlighted the fragility of
global supply networks and the importance of supply chain resilience.
4.5 Supply Theories Integrated with
Functional Equations
This section explains the most influential supply theories, aligned with the
analytical supply function discussed earlier in the chapter:
Qs = a + bP
– cC + dT + eL – fS
Where:
·
Qs = Quantity supplied
·
P = Price of the product
·
C = Cost of production
·
T = Time efficiency (or technological
capability)
·
L = Logistics infrastructure
·
S = Seasonality/perishability
·
a, b, c, d, e, f = positive or negative
coefficients depending on sensitivity
1. Law of
Supply
This classical theory states that if all other
factors remain constant, quantity supplied increases as the price increases. Mathematically,
when Qs = a + bP, with b > 0,
the slope of the curve is positive. For instance, if Qs = 20 + 4P and price
increases from ₹10 to ₹12, supply increases from 60 to 68 units. This supports
the upward-sloping nature of the supply curve.
2.
Short-run vs Long-run Supply
In the short
run, some factors like capital (K) remain fixed, making the supply
less responsive. If we modify the function as:
Qs = a + bP – cC, then c is high,
showing high cost impact due to limited flexibility.
In the long
run, firms can adjust all inputs, and dT becomes significant in the function Qs = a + bP – cC
+ dT. For example, technological advancements (like automation) increase T, thereby raising Qs over time.
3.
Marginal Cost Theory of Supply
According to this theory, producers supply
additional units until marginal cost equals price. If marginal cost (MC) = 2 +
0.5Q and market price is ₹12, then setting MC = P:
2 + 0.5Q = 12 ⇒ Q = 20 units.
This value of Q becomes the firm's optimal supply at that price point.
This aligns with our supply function where cost is a component:
Qs = a + bP – cC. When C increases due to rising MC, the total supply Qs
decreases.
4.
Elasticity of Supply
Supply elasticity measures responsiveness to
price changes.
The elasticity formula is:
Es = (% change in Qs) / (% change in P)
From Qs = 50 + 3P, if P increases from ₹10 to
₹12, Qs changes from 80 to 86.
So:
Es = [(86 – 80)/80] ÷ [(12 – 10)/10] = 0.075 / 0.2 = 0.375 (Inelastic supply)
This shows that when b is small in Qs = a + bP, elasticity is low.
5.
Cobb-Douglas Production Function (Supply Base)
The production function:
Q = A × L^α × K^β
Where L is labor, K is capital, and A is total factor productivity.
Assuming A = 1, α = 0.6, β = 0.4, and input
values L = 100, K = 64,
then Q = 1 × (100)^0.6 × (64)^0.4 ≈ 1 × 15.85 × 6.35 ≈ 100.7 units
This production-based output can be used in
the supply function, i.e.,
Qs = Q = a + bP – cC + dT, where T
includes technological or factor efficiency improvements derived from
Cobb-Douglas parameters.
6.
Agricultural Supply Response Theory
In agriculture, the supply function often
includes lag effects. A simplified form is:
Qsₜ = a + bPₜ₋₁ – cS + eL
Here, supply in period t depends on
price in period (t–1) due to seasonal
production. If prices for wheat rose in the last year, farmers respond with
increased supply this year.
Example:
Qsₜ = 40 + 2(Priceₜ₋₁) – 3(Perishability Index) + 4(Logistics Index)
7.
Behavioral Supply Theory
Behavioral economics introduces psychological
constraints and risk aversion. Firms may avoid scaling up supply even if P
increases, due to fear of regulation or uncertainty.
This may flatten or distort the standard
supply function. In such cases, b (price
coefficient) becomes smaller, and f (risk or seasonal sensitivity) becomes larger in:
Qs = a + bP – cC + dT – fR
For example, during COVID-19, hoarding and
fear caused supply to drop despite price incentives.
8.
Inventory-Based Supply Models
Supply is also shaped by inventory strategies.
If firms use Just-in-Time (JIT)
systems, the function becomes highly sensitive to logistics delays, represented in:
Qs = a + bP – cC + dT + eL – fD
Where D = Disruption delay factor.
If logistics quality L falls or
delays D increase, the available
Qs declines regardless of price.
9.
Leontief Production Function and Fixed Inputs
Here, inputs are used in fixed proportions.
The production function is:
Q = min (L/α, K/β)
Where output depends on whichever input is the limiting factor.
This makes the supply function extremely
rigid. For example, if 1 worker is needed per 1 machine, and machines are
limited, increasing labor will not increase Qs.
Hence, in such cases, supply is perfectly
inelastic:
Qs = constant, regardless of
price changes.
10.
Resource-Based Supply Theory
Firms with unique internal capabilities (e.g.,
patents, exclusive suppliers) are less influenced by market price and more by strategic factors.
A modified function could be:
Qs = a + bP – cC + dT + gR,
where R = proprietary resource
index (like access to lithium or AI tech).
This theory applies well to companies like
Tesla, which control supply via exclusive contracts rather than price-based
market incentives.
All these theories enrich our understanding of the reconstructed supply
function:
Qs = a + bP – cC + dT + eL – fS
·
Price (P) explains traditional supply behavior.
·
Cost (C) and Time (T) explain operational
constraints.
·
Logistics (L), Seasonality (S), Risk (R), and
Disruption (D) explain modern realities.
·
The elasticity, production, and inventory
theories help quantify and forecast changes in Qs.
4.6 Numerical Problem Set
Problem 1: Basic Calculation
Given Qs = 40 + 3P – 2C + T
Where P = ₹20, C = ₹5, T = 10
Calculate Qs.
Solution:
Qs = 40 + 3(20) – 2(5) + 10 = 40 + 60 – 10 + 10 = 100 units
Problem 2: Interpreting Shocks
If cost (C) rises by ₹5 and T drops to 5, what’s the new Qs?
New Qs = 40 + 60 – 2(10) + 5 = 40 + 60 – 20 + 5 = 85 units
Interpretation: A ₹5 increase in cost and 5-unit drop in time
efficiency led to a reduction of 15 units in supply.
Problem 3: Comparative Industry Analysis
Sector |
Base Price (P) |
Cost (C) |
Tech (T) |
Qs Equation |
Electronics |
₹30 |
₹12 |
8 |
Qs = 60 + 5P – 3C + 2T |
Textiles |
₹25 |
₹8 |
6 |
Qs = 55 + 4P – 2C + T |
Calculate Qs for both sectors.
Electronics
Qs = 60 + 5(30) – 3(12) + 2(8) = 60 + 150 – 36 + 16 = 190
Textiles
Qs = 55 + 4(25) – 2(8) + 6 = 55 + 100 – 16 + 6 = 145
Interpretation: Despite a lower base price, electronics
have higher Qs due to superior tech influence and sensitivity to price.
4.7 Summary and Policy Insights
·
Supply is more than price:
Non-price determinants like cost, time, perishability, and policy disruptions
critically shape supply.
·
Technology boosts elasticity:
Tech investment reduces delay and perishability risks.
·
Global dependence is a risk:
The COVID-19 case teaches that domestic sourcing and buffer inventory can
reduce shocks.
·
Policy design must consider logistics:
Merely increasing MSP or subsidies won't work unless logistics infrastructure
is upgraded
Appendix –
📊 Table 1: Comparative Supply Function Across Industries
Industry |
Qs Equation |
Interpretation |
Electronics |
Qs = 60 + 5P – 3C + 2T |
High responsiveness to price and tech, but sensitive to
cost increases |
Textiles |
Qs = 55 + 4P – 2C + T |
Moderate elasticity, benefits from low cost and average
tech dependence |
Agriculture |
Qs = 45 + 3P – 4C – 2S + L |
Highly perishable; logistics play a critical role in
supply quantity |
Pharmaceuticals |
Qs = 70 + 4P – 5C + T – D |
Vulnerable to disruption (D); strong regulatory and input
cost dependency |
Fast Food Chains |
Qs = 50 + 3P – 2C + L – S |
Seasonal variation affects fresh inventory; local
logistics boost supply reliability |
📦 Table 2: Inventory Behavior & Supply Resilience
Inventory Type |
Used By |
Supply Impact |
Advantages |
Disadvantages |
Just-in-Time (JIT) |
Electronics, Automotive |
Fast turnaround, reduced holding cost |
Cost-efficient, agile |
Disruption-prone, less buffer |
Safety Stock |
Pharma, FMCG |
Buffer against unexpected demand/supply delays |
Ensures availability |
Ties up capital |
Economic Order Quantity (EOQ) |
Retail Chains |
Optimal ordering to minimize total cost |
Efficient use of resources |
Needs accurate demand forecasting |
Seasonal Stock |
Agriculture, Apparel |
Preparedness for peak demand cycles |
Satisfies demand surges |
Risk of overstock or spoilage |
Bulk Inventory |
Hardware, Furniture |
High volume production, economies of scale |
Cost-effective in long run |
Higher storage & insurance costs |
📉 Table 3: Disruptions and Delays – COVID-19 Supply Chain
Case
Sector |
Dependency Type |
Disruption Source |
Impact on Supply Curve |
Government/Industry Response |
Pharma |
Raw Material (APIs) |
Lockdown in China (Wuhan) |
Leftward shift due to input scarcity |
Export bans, domestic API push |
Automotive |
Global Components |
Border closures, chip shortage |
Long-run supply curve flattening |
Local sourcing, chip plant investments |
Agriculture |
Seasonal Labor |
Migration & lockdown |
Supply dip, wastage of perishables |
Special trains, farmgate procurement |
Retail Grocery |
Logistics & Warehousing |
Movement restrictions |
Stockout of essentials |
E-pass systems, last-mile delivery innovations |
Textiles |
Export Dependency |
Port closures |
Delayed shipments, idle inventory |
Shift to domestic e-commerce channels |
Comments
Post a Comment